Loading...
HomeMy WebLinkAbout4.13 SMART ReportAnalysisAGENDA STATEMENT CITY CLERK FILE # 660-40 CITY COUNCIL MEETING DATE: (September 21, 1999) SUBJECT: SMART Report Analysis Report Prepared by: Richard C. Ambrose ATTACHMENTS: SMART Task Force Report RECOMMENDATION: )/Receive Report FINANCIAL STATEMENT: None DESCRIPTION: This report is in response to a proposal from the State Municipal Advisory Reform Team (SMA~.T), which was formed by State Controller Kathleen Connell in March 1999. The SMART task force was composed of representatives 0fbusiness, labor, academic and elected officials who worked to devise a proposal that would rectify the imbalance between state and local revenue support. The report was completed on August 19, 1999 and distributed to Mayors across the state asking for their written comments and support. There are three key components to the proposal. The first and most controversial is a recommendation to gradually replace the current "point of sale" sales tax distribution formula with a new formula based on population. The SMART Report contends that this will "encourage more responsible local planning." The plan uses a "90/10/100" formula. In year one, 90% of all sales tax would be apportioned among counties and cities based on their proportionate contribution to statewide retail sales the preceding year. l:his was-- recommended in order to allow local govemmeuts to be able to honor their existing bonding requirements and other agreements tied to sales tax revenues. In subsequent years, 100% of the net local sales tax gains will be apportioned by population. What this means is that, as statewide sales tax revenues increase over the next 20 years, greater portions of the sales tax will be allocated by population. This change in the sales tax allocation formula would require an amendment to the State Constitution. H/cc-forms/agdastmLdoe COPIES TO: ITEM NO. The SMART report acknowledges that there will be many communities severely impacted by the sales tax proposal. To diminish these negative affects, the Task Force proposes that the ERAF baseline be reduced by approximately $450 million annually, and return this difference to local. govemments. $150 million of this money would be specifically set aside as an inducement for the creation of a state constitutional amendment to restructure the distribution of local sales taxes. This second element of the report was apparently included to soften the fiscal blow to many communities and to help increase support for the proposal. The third component is a plan to end "unfimded state mandates." Under this proposal, the State would be required to produce an Economic Impact Projection that accurately discloses the costs to local governments of any new state law or regulation and appropriate funds to pay those costs before local governments are obligated to implement them. IMPACT ON THE CITY OF DUBLIN Due to the City of Dublin's strong retail sales base, it is estimated that City sales tax revenues would be greatly reduced under this proposal, but it is unclear by how much. It would depend on when the proposal was adopted, and how much the City's population-retail sales 'mix changes over the next 10 years. Staff has been working with the City' s financial consultants, Hinderliter de Llamas and Associates (HDL) to determine the fiscal impacts to the City of Dublin. Unfommately there has been some difficulty in securing the sales tax figures and calculation used in the SMART report. This has made it difficult to get completely accurate numbers. Although it is difficult to be entirely certain of the impacts to the City of Dublin in the long run due to the variables and uncertainties involved, it is possible to get a good idea of what the immediate impacts would be. The following are preliminary estimates of the impacts to the City of Dublin in year 1 based on the 97-98 sales tax figures. 98-99 sales tax figures for the state are not yet available. Future impacts to the City of Dublin are likely to improve modestly over time, as Dublin's population increases faster than the state average. It is important to note that these numbers are preliminary estimates and are presented onlyto approximate what is likely to occur under this proposal. A more detailed and accurate analysis will follow, as more information becomes available. 97/98 Dublin sales tax revenue 8,025,448 90% of 97/98 Dublin sales tax revenues Dublin' s share of 10% population distribution SMART proposal- combined point of sale and population distribution 7,222,903 280,460 7,503,363 Total sales tax reduction in year 1 Sales tax reduction by percent (522,085) (6.8%) 97/98 State population of 33, 226, 000 and Dublin population of 26, 725 97/98 Total State sales tax revenues (County and city distribution)- $3,487, 012, 000 It's clear from this preliminary analysis of the sales tax portion of the SMART proposal, that the City of Dublin would stand to lose considerable sales tax revenues. It is estimated that about 50% of Catifomia cities and counties would be hurt by the proposal and the other 50% would receive a sales tax windfall. To lighten the blow dealt to cities such as Dublin, the task force is recommending that the state return $450 millio,n in ERAF money that was diver~ed from local governments eight years ago in order to cope with a state budget crisis. Every city in the State of Califomia would certainly support this recommendation. City's have been fighting to~ get the ERAF money retumed ever since it was taken away. Unfortunately, the likelihood of the State giving local govemments $450 million is extremely low. A large part of the SMART report and its analysis is based on the assumption that the Govemor and State Legislators would be willing to give local govemments a share of the State's property tax revenues. This has been an extremely difficult proposition in the past, and there is no reason to believe that things will change in the near future. The current Govemor, Gray Davis has been particularly reluctant to promise any long-term State funds, fearing an economic downtown would force him to raise taxes or make deep budget cuts. Under the SMART proposal, the City of Dublin would be losing sales tax revenue in exchange for property tax money that is unlikely to ever be remmed. Even in the unlikely event that $450 million in ERAF revenues were returned to cities and counties, the City of Dublin would still stand to lose over $300,000 in total revenues. The following summarizes the estimated impact of the ERAF restoration. SMART proposal- combined point of sale and population distribution 7,503,363 SMART- additional ERAF allocation Combined sales tax redistribution and ERAF restoration Net impact to City with sales tax redistribution and ERAF restoration Net impact to City by percent 220,752 7,724,115 (301,333) 0.75%) In addition to the sales tax revenue that the City will lose, on a more fundamental note, City staff disagrees with the general statements and assumptions made by the SMART Report. The authors of the Report claim that the Report will "Incentivize cash-starved municipalities to invest in community, housing and quality of life programs--instead of erecting huge car malls on cheap land to attract sales tax revenue." Unfortunately, the authors fail to mention the real reason behind land development- economics. Auto malls and retail centers locate where there is a market and where they can make the largest profits- typically near freeways and other major transportation routes. If the State wants to do away with the fiscalization of land use, they may want to consider limiting or eliminating financial incentives given by cities to developers. The real damage is done by jurisdictions competing with each other over retail and commercial development. Cities rarely make decisions that would place an auto mall where a housing project could have gone. City planning is not done by computing the overall tax potential of a piece of land, but rather by responding to the needs and desires of the community. Furthermore, it is appropriate for sales tax revenues to be distributed based on a point of sale basis because of the expenses involved in providing and maintaining the infrastructure for a commercial development. people travel from other jurisdictions to shop in Dublin and use the City's facilities and infrastructure. Therefore it is reasonable for the City to expect a greater proportion of sales tax revenues to pay for these additional expenses. The people of Dublin should not .be burdened with these additional .costs. To distribute sales tax revenues based on population would mean that bedroom communities with ~ very little commercial or retail developments would receive more sales tax revenues than Dublin, even though their citizens frequently use Dublin's roads and services. It does not make any sense to distribute sales tax revenues based on population. The final part of the SMART report asks the State Legislature to eliminate the practice of imposing unfunded mandates on cities and counties. The City of Dublin would certainly welcome this initiative, but this too, may be unrealistic. For years the State has ignored a legal mandate to pay local governments for ' the costs imposed on them by the State. It is unclear how this proposal would change this mandate. Recommendation The League of California Cities, HDL and City staff are in the process of further analyzing the impacts of the SMART Report. The City is working to identify the long-term effects of the proposal and the impact it would have on City services. When the analysis is complete, City staff will dmf~ a letter to Controller Connell opposing the recommendations. It is expected that all pertinent information will be available and the analysis completed within the next month. At that time, staff will present the letter to the council for consideration. It is unclear at this time how much support the SMART proposal has around the State and whether any of the recommendations will ultimately be implemented. What is clear, is that it will be an extremely long and difficult process. HDL estimates that it would take a minimum of two-to-three years to gain enough support to place a constitutional amendment on the ballot. We will continue to keep the Council apprised of any significant develo ~ments. SMART Task Force Report Kathleen Connell California State ContrOller August 1999 ATTACHMENT 1 ConWoHer's Message 2 Summary of Recommendations New Local Financing Formula Funding of Local Mandates Govemment Accountability Implementation 4 4 14 15 16 Perspectives of Stakeholders 17 Building a Foundation for the Future Historical Perspective Tax Policy Intergovernmental Accountability Land Use Planning / 18 18 23 28 32 Appendices A. Percentage of Local Revenues and Expenditures for Califomia Cities and Counties (1993-1997) B. Education Revenue Augmentation Fund (ERAF) Shift (1992/1993 - 1998/1999) C. Notes to Alternative Plans and the "SMART Formula" 37 38 39 KATHLEEN CONNELL * STATE CONTROLLER 1 Today we stand on the threshold of the 21st century md all Califomians share unbridled optimism that our great State will expand its role as the intellectual and economic capital oflhis exciting new age. As Califomia's Chief Finan- cial Officer, I am concemed that we may sabotage this future unless we confront directly the current imbalance between State and local finances and forge a consensus that will retum faimess to statewide revenue allocation. We must allow our cities and counties to rebuild from the neglect of the past years and prepare for the new century. Over the past decade, local govem- ment has not been able to provide the qualily and level of services that our citizens have a right to expect be- cause the State government -- unwilling to raise taxes or cut ser- vices -- has resolved its own budget problems by expropriating property taxes, long the primary revenue resource for local govemment Califomia's remarkable economic surge over the past three years presented an oppommily for the State to reverse the annual flow of property tax diversions back to the local level. Instead, it captured almost $3.6 billion in property taxes in fiscal year 1998-1999, celebrated a $4.3 billion surplus and planned its budget accordingly. With the State experiencing unparal- leled economic grovCth and budget surpluses, the timing could not be better for addressing what I increas- ingly believe is the most crucial public policy issue facing our State and its future. If we wait until the next inevitable downturn, it will be too late to identify -- much less implement- any truly innovative strategies. Thus, in February 1999, I formed the State Municipal Adviso~ ReformTeam (SMART). The SMART Task Force was comprised of distinguished repre- sentatives of State and local govern- men,, business and labor, environmen- talists, real estate developers, and economists. I charged the Task Force members with finding an equitable solution that would assure a stable, predictable revenue stream to local govemment without jeopardizing e:dsting obligations and without raising taxes. I asked them to be creative, prapmatic and visionary. Andthey were. Their first key decision was to focus on three distinct areas in which State govemment actions have skewed local policy decisions and hampered the ability of local governments toaddress their citizens' needs. These are tax policy, intergovemmental accountability and land use planning. ]~ollowing six months of study, meetings and debate, the Task Force settled on three primmy recommendations that redefine intergovemmental icing relationships: Recommendation 1: Restructure State and Local Properly and Sales Taxes The Task Force engaged in exhaustive economic analysis to test the fiscal impacts of an innovative approach to place a "cap" on the State's diversion of property taxes revenues and apportion future local sales t~xes on KATHLEEN CONNELL ' STATE CONTROLLER 2 factors independent of point-of-sale considerations. This analysis contimed that a carefully structured formula, if implemented, will: · Generate approximately $4.5 billion in additional revenue for local govern- ment over a 10-year period; · Make a baseline reduction in EKAF property tax diversions to $3.2 billion to assist the State in funding its educa- tional obligations; · Reduce the retail fiscalization of land use at the local level by eliminating the tax incentives for poor local planning decisions. Sales tax will continue as a source of repayment for existing redevel- opment commitments by local govern- menIs and special districts; and · KEQUIRE NO NEW STATE OR LOCAL TAXES AND NO MODIFI- CATIONS OF PKOPOSITION 13. The Task Force's sales tax re-alloca- tion proposal could also be unilaterally enacted with a State financial commit- ment of $31 million based on Fiscal Year 1997-1998 sales tax revenues, an extremely moderate sum in light of the current $4.3 billion State surplus. However, if the State does not equalize sales taxes and guarantee a miramum $150 million in local assistance, a 'lmrd cap" on ERAF should be consid- ered. For that minimal investment all of the countywide allocation inequities could be offset and retail fiscalization would become a non-issue in future local planning decisions. The Task Force also strongly recommended that the State establish a prudent reserve for economic downturns and require perfor- mance budgeting of State programs as a way to fund those reserves. Recommendation 2: Eliminate "Unfunded" State Man- dates to Municipalities The Task Force was convinced that the State should be required to accurately disclose and fully fund the cost of any new law, regulation or executive order that requires imple~ mentation by local governments. Recommendation 3: Improve Efficiency and Effectiveness of Government Programs The Task Force insisted that all State programs administered by local agen- cies should h~corporate a mutual compact listing the respective obliga- tions and responsibilities of the State md localities and intergrating State funded performance based budgeting and perfont, race auditing. The SMART Task Force has provided us with an innovative blueprint. The current economic prosperity in Califor- nia will smooth the way for a relatively painless restmcturing of State and local finances. Now we need only the political will to act. By releasing this report as the Califomia State Legislature reconvenes in August 1999, the SMART Task Force urges the Legisla- ture to make this issue atop priority. Let us usher in the millennium with bold decisions that establish asolid firmncial inlhstmcttnre for all levels of Califomia's govemments and set the stage for anew Golden Era for the Golden State in the 21st century! Kathleen Connell California State Controller KATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER 3 New Local Financing Formula Discussion of Objectives For local governments to regain their fiscal heal~ two major structural changes must occur.. · Local govemments musthave a source of secure, stable, and sufficient revenues to meet local needs, indepen- dent of State control or intervention; and · Local govemments and services mandated by the State must be accom- panied by funding that is sufficient to support them The Task Force quickly concluded that the current scheme of State and local taxation in Californiahas been domi- nated by two serious problems: · The growing diversions of property tax revenues by the State fitrough its Educational Revenue Augmentation Funds OERAFs) has critically short- changed cash starved local govem- menIs; and · The distribution of the local compo- nent of the sales tax based upon point- of-sale has distorted local planning decisions by creating financial incen- fives for local govemments to promote retail outlets that generate high volume sales at the expense of housing and businesses that create well-paying jobs. This is more commonly known as "retail ~scaliTalion." To address these problems, the Task Force agreed that a maj or readjustment inthe collection and reallocation of sales taxes and property taxes is needed. This proposal to end the distribution of local sales taxes on the basis of point-of- sale will begin the transition towards distribution of revenue on the basis of populafion_ The Task Force identified multiple proposed solutions to redistrib- ute sales tax and property mx revenues that could conceptually fulfill both objectives and then quantified the impact of each altemafive formula on Califomia's local govemmenS. Review of Alternative Plans The Task Force readily concedes that the identification of these problems was not novel. Virtually every one of the groups and research organizations that have studied, and are studying Califomia's current tax structure, have identified the sameproblems. Likewise, all of these groups and organizations have recommended the adoption of some form of tax redistribu- tion targeted to accomplish three objectives: 1. Increase discretionary income for local govemment without unduly impacting State govemment or increasing taxes; 2. Redistribute sales tax revenues aniong local govemments in a manner that would be proportional to public need; and 3. Encourage balanced planning deci- sions in the future while not punishing local govemment for past planning decisions that were predicated on "point- of-sale" reimbursement The challenge was to create a solution that was economically fair across the board and capable of achieving approval ~om abroad political consensus. This is the point at which the S MART Task Force and the other groups and organi- KATHLEEN CONNELL ® STATE CONTROLLER zations diverged. This caused the Task Force's predecessors to suggest only general concepts and approaches without any fixed formulas that could be tested against real-life economic scenarios. However, the two most common approaches-- a Statewide property tax/ sales tax "swap" and asales tax allo- cated by statewide population have serious consequences on local govem- ment when actually implemented. These formulas do not result in an equitable flow of revenues to dries and counties. Alternative One- Property Tax Swap Some commentators have suggested a revenue neutral exchange fithe state- controlled ERAF property taxes for local sales taxes under the generic description of '~tax swap". The common claim of the "tax swap" supporters is that such a direct exchange statewide would create local incentives for better land use planning and an end to ~scalization. The Task Force discovered that there can never be atruly dollar-for-dollar ".swap" of ERAF property taxes and local sales taxes because local sales tax revenues are substantially greater. Even if the State attempted to exchange every ERAF dollar for identical sales mx dollars in each county, an excess of $500 million in local taxes would continue to be generated on a "point-of- sale" basis and therefore prolong retail ~scalization. Creative local elected leaders will continue to engage in furious competi- tion for business that generate retail sales so long as the oppommity exists to enhance local tax revenues. Even if the incenrives are reduced by some factor, the lack of any other politically "pain- less" method ofincreasing revenues means that any marginal tax benefits from "point of sale' will sustain retail ~sc~li7~:~fion Poor planning decisions that discrimi- nate against housing and higher income industries are the natural political by- products of ~x revenue inducements caused by the "point of sale" distribu- tion Although specifically not quanlffied in the Task Force report, the "swap" would also cause serious disruptions at the dty level because the vast majority of local sales taxes, particularly in the high growlh urban counties, are dedicated city revenue. For example in fiscal year 1996-1997, the cities of San Jose and Santa Clara combined ceived over $86 million more in sales taxes than in total property taxes. To effect a "swap" in Santa Clara County, its dries would be most impacted by the loss of sales taxes while its county government would be the favored redpient of the returning property taxes (see chart below). As a result, most of the major metropolitan areas would drown in a tide of red ink. Proportional Share of County-Wide Revenues -"!.' : $1: :::::.., Sales Tax ERAF Finally for the State to equalize for those countywide areas that would sustain a loss due to the "swap," the State would be required to backfill $252 million to the 15 impacted counties. To be compatable with the K~THLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER 5 Alternative Plan I -- Impact of Swapping Sales Taxes with the Educational Revenue Augmen- ..... 3tion Fund {ERAF') Property Tax (Amounts in Thousands) SMART Formula EQualization Alameda Alpine Amador Butte Calaveras Colusa Contra Costa Del Norte El Dorado Fresno Glenn Humboldt Impedal Inyo Kern Kings Lake Lassen Los Angeles Madera Mafin .~--,Mariposa endocino .vlerced Modoc Mono Monterey Napa Nevada Orange Placer Plumas Riverside Sacramento San Benito San Bernardino San Diego San Francisco San Joaquin San Luis Obispo San Mateo Santa Barbara Santa Clara Santa Cruz Shasta Sierra Siskiyou Sobno Sonoma Stanislaus Sutter Tehama Trinity /._.Tulare .... ,~olumne entura YoIo Yuba Total Estimated County and Property Tax Cities ERAF Current County Contributions or Property Tax and Cities Sales Sales Taxes for Contributions Taxes County and Cities 190,905 191,173 190,905 153 289 153 2,297 2,792 2,297 8,863 16,506 8,863 2,881 1,917 1,917 1,699 1,920 1,699 102,345 96,275 96,275 1,226 1,511 1,226 1 O, 500 10,490 10,490 65,197 69,651 65,197 1,997 1,895 1,895 10,847 11,127 10,847 6,904 10,768 6,904 1,768 2,169 1,768 46,966 57,805 46,966 8,606 7,492 7,492 3,995 3,245 3,245 1,208 1,834 1,208 1 ,O81,013 881,047 881 ,O47 7,233 7,251 7,233 29,435 32,017 29,435 875 1.235 875 6,684 8,111 6,684 16,295 13,838 13,838 681 584 584 1,580 1,535 1,535 28,760 37,390 28,760 12,477 12,588 12,477 7,400 7,776 7,400 208,161 360,558 208,161 20,890 31,503 20,890 1,181 1,664 1,181 88,668 123,351 88,668 113,619 129,258 113,619 2,287 3,631 2.287 126,219 144,524 126,219 191,889 284,166 191,889 138,524 111266 111,266 61,253 48,910 48,910 20,169 22,328 20,169 76,699 110,149 76,699 31,518 39,546 31,518 185,525 277,242 185,525 19,473 23,186 19~473 12,350 16,249 12,350 280 164 154 3,432 3.381 3,381 32,903 33,412 32.903 38,255 51,730 38,255 29,101 40,962 29,101 6,294 7,538 6,294 3,838 3,867 3,838 163 556 163 26,899 27,510 25,899 3,782 3,955 3,782 58, 155 72,837 58,155 15,839 17,982 15,839 4,764 3,355 3.355 3,182,917 3,487,012 2,930,164 Total Maximum Excess ERAF Swap of the Lesser Property Tax of Estimated ERAF Contributions $450 Million State over Sales Total Swap plus Excess Sales Supplement Net After Taxes Excess ERAF Taxes Distributed based Receipt of $450 remaining with remaining with remaining on ERAF Million State State State County-wide Contributions Supplement 190,905 268 26,990 26,990 153 136 22 22 2,297 495 325 325 8,863 7,643 1,253 1,253 964 2,881 407 1,372 1,699 221 240 240 6,070 102,345 14,469 20,540 1,226 285 173 173 10 10,500 1,485 1.495 65,197 4,454 9,218 9,218 102 1,997 282 384 107847 280 1,534 1,534 6,904 3,864 976 976 1,768 401 250 250 46,966 10,839 6,640 6,540 1,114 8,605 1,217 2.331 749 3,995 565 1,314 1,208 626 171 171 199,966 1,081,013 152,833 352, 800 7,233 18 1 .O23 1,023 29,435 2.582 4,162 4,162 875 361 124 124 6,684 1,428 945 945 2,457 16,295 2,304 4,761 97 681 96 193 45 1,580 223 268 28,760 8,630 4,066 4,066 12,477 111 1,764 1,764 7,400 376 1,048 1,046 208,161 152,396 29,430 29,430 20,890 10,613 2,953 2,953 1,181 483 167 167 88.668 34,684 12,536 12,536 113,619 15,639 16,063 16,063 2,287 1,344 323 323 126,219 18,306 17,845 17,845 191,889 9Z,277 27,129 27,129 27,Z58 138,524 19,584 46,842 12,343 61,253 8,660 21,003 2Q,169 2.159 2,851 2,851 76,699 33.450 10,844 10.844 31,518 8,029 4,456 4.456 185,525 91.717 26,229 26,229 19,473 3,713 2,753 2,753 12,350 3,899 1,746 1,746 116 280 40 155 51 3,432 485 537 32,903 509 4.652 4,652 38,255 13.475 5,408 5,408 29,101 11.861 4,114 4.114 6,294 1,245 890 890 3,838 29 543 543 163 393 23 23 26,899 610 3,803 3,803 3,782 173 535 535 58,155 14.682 8,222 8,2Z2 15,839 2,143 2,239 2.239 1.409 4.764 674 2,083 252,753 3,182,917 556,848 450,000 702.753 Source: State Con~'otlers Office computed based on information fTom the Board of Equalization (1997-98) and Department of Finance (1999} KATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER second alternative and the SMART ".~.s~; formula, the cost to the State would be over $700 million as opposed to $450 million. A revenue neutral property tax/sales tax swap may be appropriate and even highly productive between county and city govemments within each county, but that approach translates very poorly at the statewide level. The Task Force believed that the "swap" plan was unacceptable due to its inability to conclusively resolve fiscalization among local govemments. Alternative Two - Allocation of Sales on the Basis of Population Some observers have suggested the cessation of local sales tax revenues based upon point-of-sale in favor of a population based dislribution. This altemative's supporters argue that their ~ approach would remove tax incentives for retail fiscalization while generally focusing and equalizing tax dollars based upon each local jurisdiction's resident population. While an admirable goal in the long-term, the abrupt imple- mentation of an exclusively population- based sales tax appointment would have disastrous consequences for many ciries and Counties over the short-range. Redistribution of retail sales taxes on the basis of popularion, as contrasted with allocation of sales taxes on a point-of- sale basis, results in significant dispad- lies between jurisdictions. Those localities that have a high population relative to their sales tax collection benefit greatly while those jurisdictions with low population relative to their sales tax distribution are faced with a ~.~' seriously negative position because of their past planning decisions to focus on retail sales tax enhancement. K~THLEEN CONNELL · STt~ CONTROLV.~R 7 Alternative P)an 2 -- impact of Afiocating Sa)es Tax Based on Population Versus Point of Sa~e J-~,mounts in Thousands) SMART Formula Eoualization Current County and City Sales Taxes Alameda 191,173 Alpine 289 Amador 2,792 Butte 16,506 Calaveras 1,917 Colusa 1,920 Contra Costa 96,275 Del Norte 1,511 El Dorado 10,490 Fresno 69,651 Glenn 1,895 Humboldt 11,127 Imperial 10,768 Inyo 2,169 Kern 57,805 ' Kings 7,492 Lake 3,245 Lassen 1,834 Los Angeles 881,047 Madera 7,251 Marin 32,017 Mariposa 1,235 Mendocino 8,111 Merced 13,838 ,'~ doc 584 n o 1,535 Monterey 37,390 Napa 12,588 Nevada 7,776 Orange 360,558 Placer 31,503 Plumas 1,664 Riverside 123,351 Sacramento 129,258 San Benito 3,631 San Bernardino 144,524 San Diego 284,166 San Francisco 111,266 San Joaquin 48,910 San Luis Obispo 22,328 San Mateo 110,149 Santa Barbara 39,546 Santa Clara 277,242 Santa Cruz 23,186 ,Shasta 16,249 Sierra 164 Siskiyou 3,381 Solano 33,412 Sonoma 51,730 Stanislaus 40,962 Sutter 7,538 Tehama 3,867 Trinity 556 Tulare 27,510 ,'~-tolumne 3,955 tura 72,837 ~lo 17,982 Yuba 3 355 Total 3 487 01'2 Sales Taxes Based on Population 147,986 123 3,516 20 853 3 937 1 913 94 612 2 901 15 567 81 955 2, z80 13,231 14,736 1,885 66,946 13,248 5,708 3,515 1,007,400 11,956 25,604 1,662 9,004 21,365 1,026 1,118 40,388 12,863 9,250 286,570 23,320 2,111 152,120 121,610 4,944 170,785 294,602 81,614 57,248 24,944 74,627 42,241 177,097 26,095 17,079 331 4,577 40,280 45,809 44,701 7,919 5,749 1,363 37,506 5,487 76,607 16,395 6 235 3 487 017 Increase Net Increase (Decrease) in Additional ERAF (Decrease) in Distribution Allocation Distribution (43,187) 26,990 (16,197) (166) 22 (145) 724 325 1,049 4,347 1,253 5,600 2,020 407 2,427 (8) 240 233 (1,663) 14,469 12,807 1,390 173 1,564 5,076 1,485 6,561 12,304 9,218 21,521 885 282 1,167 2,103 1,534 3,637 3,968 976 4,944 (284) 250 (34) 9,141 6,640 15,781 5,754 1,217 6,971 2,463 565 3,028 1,682 171 1,852 126,353 152,833 279,187 4,705 1,023 5,727 (6,413) 4,162 (2,252) 427 124 550 893 945 1,838 7,527 2,304 9,831 442 96 538 (417) 223 (194) 2,998 4,066 7,064 275 1,764 2,039 1,474 1,046 2,520 (73,988) 29,430 (44,558) (8,183) 2,953 (5,229) 448 167 615 28,768 12,536 41,304 (7,647) 16,063 8,416 1,313 323 1,637 26,261 17,845 44,105 10,436 27,129 37,566 (29,652) 19,584 (10,068) 8,338 8,660 16,998 2,615 2,851 5,467 (35,522) 10,844 (24,678) 2,695 4,456 7,151 (100,145) 26,229 (73,915) 2,909 2,753 5,662 830 1,746 2,576 167 40 207 1,196 485 1,681 6,869 4,652 11,520 (5,921) 5,408 (512) 3,739 4,114 7,853 381 890 1,270 1,882 543 2,424 807 23 830 9,996 3,803 13,799 1,533 535 2,067 3,770 8,222 11,992 (1,587) 2,239 652 2 880 67x~ 3 553 (0~ 450 DO0 450 O00 Source: State Controller's Office computed based on information from the Board of Equalization (1997-98) and Department of Finance (1999) KATHLEEN CONNELL ' STATE CON"rROLLEK 8 The SMART Formula In an effort to mitigate the negative results that are generated by either a property tax swap or asales tax distri- bution based solely on population, the SMART Task Force developed a formula utilizing an approach that ensures fairness in revenue distribution for local entities and the State, and requires neither new taxes nor modifi- cafiom to Proposition 13. In order to adjust sales taxes partially based on a county 's population, rather than where the sale occurred, the current percentage of sales tax revenues distributed county-wide and the per- centage of population by county were compute& This total represents what jurisdictions countywide would nor- mally receive under the current 1% allocation of taxable sales. These percentages were weighted and then multiplied by the total sales tax revenues distributed in fiscal year 1997-1998, because the 1998-1999 sales tax figures were not available at the time the report was written. This was done to determine the impact of distributing some of the sales tax revenue on population versus a point- of-sale basis. To initiate the transition away from local govemments' dependency on point-of-sale distribu- tion, the Statewide sales tax revenue was redistributed so 90% was based on the previous point-of-sale method and 10% was based on population. This resulted in 15 of the 58 county- wide areas receiving less sales tax than they would have under the previous method and 43 receiving more. Under the SMART formula, all future increases in statewide sales tax rev- enues would be distributed exclusively; upon populatior~ As the growth of retail sales tax revenues over the next quarter centuW eventually equals and exceeds current statewide sales tax revenues, population will become the dominant factor in sales tax distribu- tion. The '~istoric sales tax base" that comprises 90% of the formula in the first year will gradually become an artif act. Finally, in order to provide the counties with some relief from the ERAF shift, the Task Force proposes an ERAF baseline reduction to approximately $3.2 billion. The formula will also result in a $450 million increase to local property tax revenues which will be redistributed statewide based on the proportionate county-wide ERAF contributions for the fiscal year. A limited number of ERAF contributions had to be estimated as data is not available. The overall result of the SMART proposal, which reallocates sales taxes based on population and historic point- of-sale, and allocates $450 million in funding to offset the loss of property tax revenue from the EKAF shift, is a net increase in tax revenues on a countywide basis for all 58 Califomia counties. There are a handful of cities which will experience a reduction in sales tax revenues under the SMART Formula when 10% of the sales tax revenues are initially shifted to a population basis. Many of these municipalities should be able to mitigate their losses by eng~oing in an intra-county swap o sales taxes for a greater share of property taxes within their municipal KATHLEEN CONNELL" STATE CONTROLLER 9 boundaries. However, there are a handful of cities who will be signi~- canfly impacted during the transition. These are the cities which have over- loaded their commercial centers with vast auto malls and have failed to fully develop their residential and non-retail business and industrial areas. Cities that have historically abused retail ~scalization the most will have the greatest challenges during transition. The Task Force was convinced that the restmcturing of state and local taxes would be most effective, if the suggested changes to the sales tax and property tax were undertaken in tandem. The SMART tax plan has been crafted and tested to take advantage of the counter-balancing economic effects of the proposed sales tax and property tax re-alloca~ lions. In addition, the Task Force members believed that any state and local tax proposal that did not com- pensate for the years of financial imbalance that have impacted Califomia's local govemments would be grossly inadequate. In the 1999-2000 budget year the State has already earmarked $300 million for local assistance. This money, if redistributed according 10 the SMART formula and guaranteed each succeeding year, would account for all but another $150 million of the fully funded version recommended by the Task Force. However, if the annual expenditure of $450 million is too ambitious for some state officials, the Task Force can offer a "discount" option of only adopting that part of the SMART tax plan which reallocates sales taxes. If the State is willing 10 spend approxi- mately $31 million, based on fiscal year 1997-1998 sales tax revenue distribution, 10 offset the projected countywide deficits in 15 California counties, future local planning decisions will be immediately ben- eftted by the elimination of the "point-of-sale" tax distribution that encourages the pursuit of large retail businesses. The Task Force believes that the financial crisis at the state and local level is 10o severe 10 adopt only a revenue-neutral proposal. If the State on an annualized budget basis fails 10 transfer to local goverment an amount sufficient for sales tax equalization for that fiscal year plus another $150 million increment, a 'Ixard cap" should be applied to ERAF. In lhis manner, the State will not receive any appreciation in property tax revenues. While not addressing the serious revenue problems being experienced by local govemments due to the diversion of properly taxes, even this lower cost approach could end the ~scalizafion of local land use plan- ning. By itself; it would be a noble achievement. The'Task Force mem- bers also cautioned that a failure by the State to take advantage of the more comprehensive opportunities offered by the entire SMART tax plan would be tra~cally myopic. The Task Force chose to exclude all special districts and less than county- wide districts from the reallocation formula for three reasons. First, those districts were created by the voters in those districts based on very specific KATHLEEN CONNELL * STATE CONTROLLER 10 representations and understandings. It would be improper to alter those elements after the fact. Second, the financing arrangements for those districts are both sensitive and complex. The Task Force felt it unwise to disrupt those credit ar- rangements. Finally, since those districts are limited in purpose and authority to a single, narrow concern, they do not share the general planning authority that dries and counries have used to promote retail ~scaliZation. Curren~y the intm-county allocation of tax revenues results in a pattern in which all allies are disproportionately dependent on sales tax revenues while county govemments rely disproportionately on property taxes. This pattem causes two serious problems even under the SMAKT formula_ First, the excessive dependency of any government on a dominant, single source of tax revenue height- ens the fiscal vulnerability of that government during economic cycles. Since property taxes are generally inelastic and respond relatively slowly to economic upswinSs, the revenue growth of county govem- ments consisten~y has lagged behind the prosperity of cities within those counries during periods of economic growth. Conversely, the extreme reliance on hiShly volatile sales tax revenues by dries has clramarically intensified the negative impact during economic downturns. Second, if cities increased their stakehold interest in property taxes, they would be ~nandally encouraSed to favor planning dealsions that promote high quality residential and commerdal developments that could maximize each city' s share of prop- erty taxes. In this manner, the in- creased munidpal service demands of residential and commercial develop- menIs can be mitigated once the dries exchange their historical share of sales taxes for an increased share of their county's property taxes. Also, by engaging in a revenue neutral "tax swap" at the intra-county level that balances the sources of county and dty revenues, both counties and cities can benefit from a blended stabilized tax base. Such a blending will adjust for economic conditions and facilitate constmcrive growth. Spedfying a genetic intra-county tax distribution formula was beyond the scope of the Task Force. It is, however, an important final component in the tax reallocation recommendation and should be addressed by cib' and county elected officials in conjunc- tion with the proposed tax changes. In combination with the distribution of statewide local sales taxes sug- gested by the SMART formula, a balanced intra-county sales tax/ property tax swap can replace retail "fiscalizarion" with constructive land use policies. Economic Scenarios The Task Force has anticipated the critical observation that the SMART plan appears to yield spectacular results during periods of economic prosperity, but may result in negative '~ consequences when an economic downram forces austerity. Admittedly KATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER ll the proposals recommended by the Task Force will not immunize Cali- fomia from future recession, nor will they provide a panacea to spare govemment leaders from the difficult decisions necessary in hard times. However, the implementation of the Task Force' s recommendations offers mitigating aspects during difficult times: · First, by providing both state and local governments with a better mix of elastic and inelastic revenue sources, no sin~e level of govemment will have its revenues disproportionately depressed in times of economic slow-down; and · Second, by better solidifying the funding responsibilities of state and local govemments, one level ofgovem- ment will not be able to resolve its issues by shifting problems to another level. All levels of government will be in the same boat sharing a co-dependent interest in remaining afloat. It is undeniable that the State will need to make the greatest adjustment in anticipation of and during the next recession. The combination of the education funding obligations imposed by Proposition 98, fixed debt servicing obligations and the proposed "cap" on property tax diversions will challenge current and future State leaders. Those challenges, however, require only a minimum of financial planning and a modicum of political courage. Since it is inevitable that the astound- ing growth of the late 1990's will not continue on its current robust perfor- mance pace, the State must begin to plan for afumre with less economic resources now rather than later. Aggres- sive performance auditing throughout State govemment will expose waste and inefficiency. Those savings can be added to regular set-asides to create a prudent reserve as ahedge against %ad times." This is the same minimal precautionary financial planning that the State demands from local school districts. The State could profit and protect itself by following its own advice. In a tree economic catastrophe, it may be necessary for the State to temporarily increase the propemd tax diversions through the ERAFs. The Task Force believed that such a sim__afi_'on is highly unlikely, but also did not want to foreclose the possiblity should such an improbable scenario occur. Therefore, the Task Force would consider a "suspension" of the ERAF limitation, if it was accompanied by a simultaneous "suspension" of the State's Proposi- tion 98 educational obligations. Any shortfall from the emergency year would then be repaid to local govem- ments in the same manner that shortfalls due to suspension of Proposition 98 are repaid to school - districts. The looming retirement of the baby boomers' generation, the exploding birth rate from the "boomers' echoes" and the relatively small number of Califomia workers in their prime earning years will very' soon put Califomia's foresight and financial planning to a rigorous test. Without immediate steps to compensate for those inevitable financial tensions, no comprehensive State and local financial reform plan -- current or proposed -- will save us from any I~HLEEN CONNELL" STATE CONTROLt-F-P, 12 Alternative 3 -- The SMART Ran (Amounts in Thousands) Sales Taxes Based on 90% Current County Sales Taxes Point of Sale Increase Additional and City Sales Based on and 10% on (Decrease) in ERAF Net Increase in Taxes Population Population Distribution Allocation Distribution Alameda 191,173 147,986 186,855 (4,319) 26,990 22,671 Alpine 289 123 273 (17) 22 5 Amador 2,792 3,516 2,865 72 325 397 Butte 16,506 20,853 16,941 435 1,253 1,688 Calaveras 1,917 3,937 2,119 202 407 609 Co lusa 1,920 1,913 1,919 (1) 240 239 Contra Costa 96,275 94,612 96,108 (166) 14,469 14,303 Del Norte 1,51 1 2,901 1,650 139 173 312 El Dorado 10,490 15,567 10,998 508 1,485 1,992 Fresno 69,651 81,955 70,882 1,230 9,218 10,448 Glenn 1,895 2,780 1,984 88 282 371 Humboldt 11,127 13,231 11,338 210 1,534 1,744 Imperial 10,768 14,736 11,165. 397 976 1,373 Inyo 2,169 1,885 2,141 (28) 250 222 Kern 57,805 66,946 58,719 914 6,640 7,554 Kings 7,492 13,246 - 8,068 575 1,217 1,792 Lake 3,245 5,708 3,492 246 565 811 Lassen 1,834 3,515 2,002 168 171 339 Los Angeles 881,047 1,007,400 893,682 12,635 152,833 165,469 Madera 7,251 I 1,956 7,721 470 1,023 1,493 Marin 32,0! 7 25,604 31,376 (641) 4, 162 3,520 Mariposa 1,235 1,662 1,278 43 124 166 Mendocino 8,111 9,004 8,201 89 945 1,034 Merced 13,838 ' 21,365 14,591 753 2,304 3,057 Mod oc 584 1,026 628 44 96 140 Mono 1,535 1,118 1,493 (42) 223 I 82 Monterey 37,390 40,388 37.690 300 4,066 4,366 Napa 12,588 12,863 12,616 27 1,764 1,791 Nevada 7,776 9,250 7,923 147 1,046 1,194 Orange 360,558 286,570 353,159 (7,399) 29,430 22,031 Placer 31,503 23,320 30,685 (818) 2,953 2,135 Plumas 1,664 2,111 1,708 45 167 212 Riverside 123,351 ~ 152,120 126,228 2,877 12,536 15,413 Sacramento 129,258 121,610 128,493 (765) 16,063 15,299 San Benito 3,631 4,944 3,762 131 323 455 San Bernardino 144,524 170,785 147,150 2,626 17,845 20,471 San Diego 284,166 294,602 285,209 1,044 27,129 28,173 San Francisco 111,266 81,614 108,301 (2,965) 19,584 16,619 San Joaquin 48,910 57,248 49,744 834 8.660 9,494 San Luis Obispo 22.328 24,944 22,590 262 2,851 3,113 San Mateo _ 110,149 74,627 106,596 (3,552) 10,844 7,292 Santa Barbara 39,546 42,241 39,816 269 4,456 4,725 Santa Clara 277,242 177,097 267,228 (10,014) 26,229 16,215 Santa Cruz 23,186 26,095 23,477 291 2,753 3,044 Shasta 16,249 17,079 16,332 83 1,746 1,829 Sierra 164 331 181 17 40 56 Siskiyou 3,381 4,577 3,500 120 485 605 Solano 33,412 40,280 34,099 687 4,652 5,339 Sonoma 51,730 45,809 51,138 (592) 5,408 4,816 Stanislaus 40,962 44,701 41,336 374 4,114 4,488 Sutter 7,538 7,919 7,576 38 890 928 Tehama 3,867 5,749 4,055 188 543 731 Trinity 556 1,363 637 81 23 104 Tu lare 27,510 37,506 28,509 1,000 3,803 4,803 Tuolumne 3,955 5,487 4,108 153 535 688 Ventura 72,837 76,607 73,214 377 8,222 8,599: Yolo 17,982 16,395 17,823 (159) 2,239 2,081 Yuba 3 355 6 ?35 3 6zl3 '288 674 96'2 Total 3 487.012 3.487.012 3.487.0'1:2 (0~ 450 000 450.000 Source: State Controller's Office computed based on information from the Board of Equalization (1997-98) and Department of Finance (1999) KATHLEEN CONNELL ' STATE CONTROLLER 13 poor choices our State leaders may make now and in the immediate future. Political procrastination, fueled by the blind hope that the. inevitable collapse will occur during a successor's term of office, is a betrayal of the citizens of Califomia_ SMART Plan 's Value The Task Force engaged in several calculations testing the fiscal impacts of this innovative approach. The analy- sis confirmed that the SMART formula was an approach that pro- - moted long-term economic develop- ment without undermining current obligations. Over its initial ten-year period, the SMART formula will: · Generate over $4.5 billon dollars in additional revenue for local govem- ment; · Allow the State to maintain a portion of the ERAF to substantially fund its education obligations over the next 10 years; and · Eliminate the incentive for retail '~iscalization" of land planning decisions. Funding of Local Mandates Discussion of Objectives Curren~y the State violates the Crann Initiative and the California Constitution by imposing expensive mandates on localities and then routinely proclaiming them to be neither mandates nor expensive. Thereafter, localities receive no financial reimbursement mill their claims have wound their way through lhe cumbersome Commission on State Mandates process. The economic impact on localities in the interim is negative. The objective of the SMART Task Force with regard to the funding of State mandates was to develop a mechanism that would ensure all State mandated programs are ad- equately funded by the Legislature before implementation. Presentation of Plan The Task Force recommends that whenever the State enacts a new program or increases the level of service that local governments are required to implement, the State should be required to contemporane- ously appropriate funding to cover local governments' costs of compli- ance. In the absence of such funding, local agencies should not be required to implement the new law, executive order or regulatiorL For these cases, local agencies should be allowed to seek a court-ordered Preliminary Stay of Operation suspending the enforcement of any portion of a statute, executive order, or State agency regulation imposing any additional mandated costs on local govemment while a test claim is pending before the Commission on State Mandates. Exceptions would be allowed if the State establishes that the appropriated reimbursement funds deposited in the State Mandate Claims fund for the specific mandate are equal to at least 75% of its reasonably projected annual costs. The Stay of Operation will remain in effect until: a) A supplemental deposit brings the balance to 75% of the reasonably projected annual costs; or K~THLEEN CONNELL ' STATE CONTROLLER 14 b) The commission denies the test dairn; or c) The local agency abandons its test daim In addition, the Task Force recom- mended that when local govemments agree to administer a State program, bilateral compacts should be formed that incorporate spedtic expectations and obligations of the State and local partners. These compacts should include a commitment by the State to fund and by the locality to implement effective performance-based budget- ing and performance auditing that would be appropriate to the specific program. Value of the State Mandate's For- The formula devised by the SMAKT Task Force requires the State to affix an accurate price tag on every proposed mandate and concurrently appropriate the amount of money necessmy to ensure that the local agency is fully reimbursed. Future decisions on whether to impose a mandate will be weighed against the related cost. Governmental Accountability The Task Force found that aparticu- larly sensitive area of tension between the State government and the localities involves the several State-funded programs, such as health and welfare, that are administered through local govemments. State representatives complained that their funding cannot be tracked to concrete results once it reaches local hands. Local representa- fives countered that agreements with the State seem to be in a constant state of flux. Everyone agreed that a lack of ~ effective communication is the mot cause for the impasse. Bilateral Compa~ The recommendation made by the Task Force mirrors the very successful approach incorporated into the State's '%Vorkfare" program The critical component is a bilateral compact between the funding State and the administering local government that clearly and unequivocally sets forth the obligations and the expectations of both parties. The greater the level of specificity and precision in the language of the compa~ the more likely that accountability and respon- sibility will produce the anticipated results. Several of the Task Force participants~w/ suggested that these bfiateml compacts should include the most current budget- ing and auditing tools in order to provide an accurate appraisal of performance. Performance-based budgeting and performance auditing, already established as powerful main- stays in the budget process of many govemments throughout Calffomia and the nation, are useful weapons in the war against waste. Since the savings g~erated would be realized by the State, the Task Force was adamant that the costs of implementation should be a State expense exclusively. Finally, the Task Force was insistent that performance auditing should become a regular tool of government applied across the board and not as only a punitive device. The potential benefits of effective performance auditing are too impressive to limit its application. KATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER 15 While outside the scope of this study, the Task Force encourages State govemment to increase its use of these approaches to generate more effective and efficient control of operations. The oppommity to realize substantial savings is too great to ignore. Implementation The SMART Task Force realizes that the proposals and recommendations contained ii~ this report will require statutory amendments and may require a constitutional amendment for full implementation. As imple- mentation of the proposals contained in lhis report will require a wide range of support from throughout the State, the Task Force intends to circulate the report to, and seek input from, elected State and local officials, business, union, and community leaders and Statewide stakeholder organizations. K437HLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONrrROLLER 16 The Task Force's membership repre- sentedmost elements ofthe wide spectrum of divergent economic and political interests that together create the California political mosaic. Therefore, the Task Force was acutely aware flint each positive concession made in one direction otten generated anegative consequence --sometimes unintended -- in another direction. The generous input from the Task Force members was essential in idenlifying theSe trade- offs. The challenge to balance these perspectives without losing sight of the ultimate goals was more daunting. Even within a category ofstakeholders, the Task Force found variances in · perspectives and interest For example, 'Yetailers" do not speak with a common voice. The concems of"Main Street" shop owners and "Big Box" conglomer- ates are often diametrically opposed. Saturation advertising anddiscount prices by 'Big Box" retailers frequently threaten the survival tithe local businesses. Educational interests, protected by Proposition 98 guarantees, see the world from a much different perspec- tive t~han higher education interests who must compete for their slice of the general revenues. The constimencies of State government unions often have demands tl'mt are incompatible with their union colleagues who belong to local public employee associations. Even among city and county leaders, the economic profiles of those they represent create alliances and conflicts independent of the level ofgovemment they represent Much of the time spent developing the Task Force' s recommendations was devoted to accommodating needs, moderating consequences and generally injecting notions of fairness and equity. Obviously, ffany one of the spedtic interest groups that partidpated in this exercise constructed an "ideal solution" from their own perspectives, there would be little similarities with this Task Force's recommendations. Our Task Force members were consistently able to put aside professional self interests and adopt an attitude for the greater good Hearing the sincere, candid concems of their counterparts encour- aged constructive and creative compro- mise. The valuable recommendations contained in this report reflect that process. The Task Force acknowledges that its recommendations cannot satisfy every goal of every group with astake in the relationghi p of State and local govern- ment in Califomia. However, the Task Force does believe that its recommen- dalions will create the financial incen- tives to form a more productive, better balanced future in which all stakehold- ers will make the necessary adjustments and ultimately prosper. I~L4,THLEEN CONNELL ' ST~E CONTROLLER 17 In February 1999, State Controller Kaltaleen Cormell appointed a Task Force called the State Municipal Advisory Reform Team (SMART) and charged it with the goal of improving the fiscal relationship betwere State and local govemment in California. Com- posed of public and private sector leaders, labor and business representa- rives, county and dty offidals, commu- nity leaders, academics, and elected officials, this Task Force represented a wide range of perspectives and exper- rise. In March 1999, the Task Force began a series of meetings throughout Califomia, inviting experts to address specificissues. The following objectives guided the Task Force: Tax Poficy - Identify stable and reliable sources of revenue for local govem- merit that are not susceptible to diver- sion or preemption by State govem- Intergovernmental Accountability - Identify budgetmy and auditing pro- cesses that will ensure the delivery of vital local govemment services; provide a reliable, predictable, and adequate source of revenue; ~d fully mitigate the expense of complying with State- mandated programs; and Land Use Planning - Recommend local government land use politics lhat can promote long-term employment growth and sustainable economic prosperity without unduly jeopardizing traditional sources of local govemment financial support. Historical Perspective To better understand the Task Force members' comideration of these issues, a brief review of three laws is helpful. These laws, approved by voters and lawmakers over the past three decades, have had amajorimpact onlocal governments' fiscal affairs. Much of the Task Force's deliberations centered on the impact of these laws and the reforms that should be considered to restore balance to the State-local tax structure. Proposition 13 The largest source of revenue for Califomia's local governments was historically propert~ taxes. That changed with passage of Propos~rion 13 in 1978 (California Consti~tion article YlTI A). This measure cut local property ~ revenues by 57%. Proposition 13 amended the California Constitution to provide that: · General property mx cannot exceed 1% of assessed value; · Property is taxed based on its 1975 assessment or its value when acquired~ · Any new "special" taxes from count, city, or school dis~icts must be passed by nvo-th~rds of the electorate; · Property ~ces are to be collected by counties on behalf of all local govern- memal entities, the proceeds to be apportioned according to law to the · Any new State taxes must be passed by a ~vvo-thirds vote of the Legislature; · State and local government cmmot impose any other taxes on property; and KATHLEEN CONNELL ' STATE CONTROLLER 18 sage 'wtLs' projected ~.m'~nts has bee~ t~te hms · The base-year acquisition value cannot increase more than 2% a year. Among the exceptions to the acquisi- tion-value assessment system set by Proposition 13 are: · Market value, if lower than inflated acquisition value, establishes value for tax purposes; · Property transferred between spouses, parents, children, grandparents, and grandchildren is not massessect; · Certain other events, addedto Article X/IIA by voter approval in theyears since 1978, do not trigger re,assess- ment; and · Property assessed by the State Board of Equalization, such as property of State-regulated utilities, is not subject to the acquisition-value lirnitatiop_ The immediate result of Proposition 13 's passage was projected to be at least a $6 billion loss of local revenues to counties, cities, school districts, and special districts. The long-term impact on local govemments has been the loss of fiscal autonomy. Local entities could no longer set their own tax rate at alevel to meettheirneeds. Cities adjusted in a variety of ways. Some cut jobs and services to save money and/or introduced or increased charges for services such as sewage treatment. These dedicated revenues are now the largest source of income for most cities, followed by sales tax rev- enues. Such services as electricity, water and sewage are provided from these revenues. Counties confronted a different set of challenges following Proposition 13. As they already faced more legal constraints on their taxing powers, most counties had to cut spending deeply. Rural counties especially found it difficult to meet Slate spending requirements. At the other end of the State, Orange County approved Calffomia's first toll road inhalfa century when it could not afford to build a new fleeway. Prior to passage of proposition 13 in 1978, federal, State, and county govemments contributed 27% of all city revenues. By fiscal year 1995-1996, .this supportwas just 13%. State assistance to cities now consists of motor vehicle license fees, gasoline taxes, reimbursement of certain man- dated costs, and homeowners' property tax relief reimbursements. Califomia's current allocation of property taxes varies among different areas depending upon lhe historic property tax levels and which agencies provide given serdces in an area However, on average, a city resident's properly tax revenues are distributed as follows: City, 14%; County, 16%; State/ Schools, 52%; and Special Districts, 18%. Proposition 98 Proposition 98, approved by the voters in 1988, amended Califomia Constitu- tion, Article XVI, section 8 to require the State to commit a prescribed amount of State funding to school districts and community college dis- uicts. The State's contribution to schools would never be less than the percentage of State General Fund revenues allocated to schools in fiscal year 1986-1987, which was 40%. Though not anticipated at the time it was adopted, Proposition 98 eventtmlly would impact local funding. This began KATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER occurring in fiscal year 1992-1993 when the State, facing a severe budget shortfail, opted to require local govern- ments to shift property taxes to schools. The Legislature directed each county auditor to establish a special fund, the Educational Revenue Augmentation Fund, or ERAE Using a formula established by the Legislature, county auditors were directed to reduce the allocation of property taxes that each local government entity would other- wise receive and place the diverted funds into the ERAF. The ERAF funds were allocated to local school districts, but only if the alloca- tion would result in dollar-for-dollar savings to the State. The Legislature then reduced the State allocation to schools (the "backfill" amounts) by the amount funded through local ERAFs, approximately $1.2 billion in fiscal year 1992-1993. The practice was continued the follow- ing year, based on new legislation that required the following: 1. The amount of property tax deemed allocated to each county, or city and county in the prior fiscal year was reduced by an amount equal to 80 cents per resident. Similar reductions were required for cities. 2. Property tax allocalions for each county were reduced in accordance with calculations in the "Eslimated County Property Tax Transfer Under Governor's May Revision Proposal," published by the Legishtive Analyst's Office (1993). As in the prioryear, this shift was intended to reduce the State obligation under Proposition 98 by an equal amount. Once again, the Legislature calculated the percentage of General Fund revenues due the schools as if the fiscal year 1993-1994 tax shift had also happened in fiscal year 1986-I 987, thus reducing the State's potential educa- tional funding obligations as a part of the State budget from 40% to 34%. Since each ERAF is defined as a "school entity" and has been granted the status of a governmental entity, each ERAF is due an allocated "share" of the property tax. The amount of property tax revenues shifted from what local governments would have received without ERAFs continues to grow as gross annual property tax receipts increase. The ERAF shift reached $3.6 billion as of fiscal year 1998-1999. Proposigon 4: The Reimbursement Process for State-Mandated Actiriges The concept of State reimbursement to local agencies and school districts for mandated activities originated in the Property Tax Relief Act of 1972, Senate Bill 90, Chapter 1406, Statutes of 1972, commonly known as SB 90. The primary purpose of SB 90 was'to limit the ability of local agencies and school districts to levy taxes. As an offset for these State-imposed limita- tions, the Legislature declared its intent to reimburse local agencies and school districts for the costs of new programs or increased levels of service mandated by State government. In 1979, the votes approved Proposition 4, the Gann Initiative, which added article XIII B to the California Consti- tution. Section 6 of article XIII B states that, whenever the Legislature or any State agency mandates a new program KATHLEEN CONNELL' STATE CONTROLLER 20 or a higher level of service on local govemment, the State must reimburse the associated costs, with certain exceptions: 1) mandates requested by the local agency; 2) legislation deeming a new crime or changing an existing definition of a crime; 3) a mandate that existed prior to January 1, 1975; or, 4) when the federal government bypasses the State and direc~y imposes costs on local agencies for fedemily mandates pro.grams. Given that this constitutional amend- ment was primarily concemed with imposing appropriation limits on the tax proceeds of both State and local government, Section 6 of article XIII B was superimposed on SB 90. Originally, the Board of Control was identified as the body with the authority to hear and decide claims requesting reimbursement of costs mandated by the State. Subsequenfiy, on January 1, 1985, the Commission on State Mandates was created as a quasi-judicial, deliberative body with the primary responsibility to hear and decide claims brought by local agencie~ and school districts that believe they are entitled to reimbursement for costs mandated by the State. The Commission currently consists of seven voting members in three catego- ries: constitutional members (the State Controller and the State Treasurer); executive branch (the Director of the Depamnent of Finance and the Director of the Office of Planning and Re- search); and three public members. California Government Code Section 17525 (b) requires that, of the three public members, one must have ~/ experience in public finance, and two must be elected local officials from either a city counc~, a county board of supervisors, or a governing board of a school district. All public members are appointed by the Governor, subject to Senate confirmation, and serve a term of four years, subject to renewal. The traditional parties before the Commission are local governments, school districts, special districts, and affected State agencies such as, the Department of Finance or the State Controller's Office. Even though both of these State offices have votes on the Commission, there has never been a disqualification imposed on a voting member. Instead, a majority of the members have consistently left the decision to recuse on an item to the ~/ member with the perceived conflict. This has sometimes increased the dismist by local governments and school districts appearing before the Commission. The projected elapsed time from the Efiing ofatest claim until the Commis- sion finally approves a Statewide Cost Estimate for inclusion in the "Local Government Claims Bill" is approxi- mately 18 months, assuming there are no unforeseen complications causing further delay. Whenever a local government claimant or an affected State agency is the recipient of an unfavorable determina- tion by the Commission, the dissatisfied party may challenge the decision by filing an action in Superior Court, an increasingly technical process that can take several years before final judg- ment. KATI-ILEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER 21 Even a resolution of all of the admin- istrative and judicial procedures does not translate into immediate reim- bursement for the expense of a State- mandated program. The local claim- ants must then present detailed documentation supporting their reimbursement claims to the State Controller 's Office for review. A disagreement at that point brings the parties back to the Commission with an Incorrect Reduction Claim. As a result of this process, some test claims filed in 1992 are still pending. Meanwhile, the affected local govern- ments are obligated to fully perform as the State has mandated, trying to finance compliance costs from a smaller revenue base. KATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER Tax Po$icy In considering ideas for constructive change in the structure of the financial relationship among the State, local govemments, and the Califomia taxpaying public, both individual and business, the SMART Task Force subcommittee on tax policy recoLmi Tixt the status quo could prove a powerful opponent. Local govemments- county and city, rural and urban - all struggle to secure the financial resources required to provide the level of service their public needs, expects, and desires. Success comes to different areas in different degrees and by different means. Yet each locality strives to locate depend- able revenue sources. For some, it is growing tourism in order to secure the sales and hotel occupancy tax revenues toudsm brings. Other localities have encouraged development with an eye toward higher property values and the resulting increase in property tax revenues. Still others have tumed to retail or auto malls to draw consumers and their sales tax dollars from sur- rounding areas. Over the years, local govemments, communities, and businesses have made decisions and planned forthe future based on the incentives built into the current tax structure. Changes in tax systems and relationships are not easily made. It is axiomatic that any prescrip- tion for change will create winners and losers. Yet a systemthat does not deliver adequate resources fairly or efficiently requires change for a better and more secure future. As members of the tax policy subcommittee noted one size does not fit all; even when change is initiated, consideration must be given to the range of local situa- tions. Need for Local Control The lax policy subcommittee believes policy makers, in undea'taking change in local govemment icing, should make certain to retain a focus on local control. Local govemments are best able to determine local needs and should be given the ability to set up revenue streams to meet those needs. Currently, local governments often must chase grant monies established by State or federal authorities. Often, the macro choices the State or federal govemment makes may not be the choices local govemment representatives would select fortheir own community. Indeed,'~'/ although money may be available, a local govemment' s failure to adequately address locally voiced needs could be related to factors beyond the local govemment's control. When the State or federal government releases ftmds to localities to address what may be perceived as peculiarly local problems, that money often comes with strings attached. In many such cases, the local govemrnent is not truly flee to deter- mine how best to expend those funds in the context of its community. Filters for Any Proposal The tax policy subcommittee recom- mended a series of"filters" for analyz- ing the feasibility of any suggested solution to the revenue challenges facing local govemments. These filters are: Stability, Predictability, Reliability, Faimess, Connection to Services, Accountability, Economic Efficiency, Kn}XLE~.N CONNELL · STATi CONTaOLL~ 23 and Viability. While some may appear synonymous, each has a distinct meaning. The filter definitions are: Stability - Whether the solution will provide astable revenue stream to local govemment so it is not unduly sub- j ected to the vagaries of the business cycle and can provide a generally stable level of service to the public. Impor- tanfly, the subject of the tax should not be so easily moved lhat people could make tax considerations thek decision point; Predictabil~'ty - Whether the solution will provide a predictable revenue stream so taxpayers can budget appro- priately for their tax obligations and local governments can have a realistic basis on which to plan expenditures and savings for an improved level of service to the public; importantly, the fiscal pressures of State govemment should not change the amount of money flowing to local govemment; Reliability - Whether the solution will assure that the revenue source to local govemment will not be withdrawn. Fairness - Whether the solulion will be fair in terms of its impact among classifications of taxpayers or among taxpayers generally; Connection to Services - Whether the solulion will provide a revenue stream that is connected or reasonably related to services provided by the local govemment to the taxpayers who fund the revenue stream; Accountability - Whether the solution will provide an auditable tax melhod to ensure proper and full collection and to allow local govemmentto be held accountable for any changes; Economic Efficiency - Whether the solution will provide a tax that will be a natural reflection of the marketplace and will minimize tax avoidance planning by not unduly influencing taxpayerbehavior, and Viability - Whetherthe solution will create atax method to make the solution polilically viable (and even acceptable) wheretaxpayers orlocal governments might otherwise be drawn to oppose the solution were it to be broadly stated. Property Tttres are Local Revenues The tax policy subcommittee considered whether property taxes should be permanently returned to local govem- menIs and schools and not be used to absorb the State govemment's General Fund obligalions. The justifications for this consideration were simple: the property tax is a traditional revenue source for local govemment in Califor- nia; the services provided by local govemment have a close and substanlial connection to the property wiffin the local government's jurisdiction; and the perception of the general rexpaying public is that the property taxes it pays stay wi~fin lhe local community. However, while the elimination of all property tax funding for state govem- ment services works in principle, the Task Force' s projections demonstrate that it collapses in practice. The subcommittee believes the State should undertake full funding for items that are truly within the Legislature' s purview and responsibility, such as the trial courts. Proposition 13 is Here to Stay According to conventional wisdom,. the I~rHLEEN CONNw.~,~, · Sr~r~ CoNr~o~um historicMjy h~.bee~ im~r~ax~ disc. reti~rm .rj., reve~e,sou~e ~br go~-eae~. 7~e concluded that gr~wth ~ k~csLsales rise tax' reveR~es be diocated ~a~ig vsdous o~ a per capita bas~ ra~er ~ ~e c~'reng financial problems of lo cal govemment and the proliferation of fees and other charges are due to Proposition 13 and its progeny. While Proposition 13 was a reaction to the financial stresses property owners faced during a time of rapid value increases and tax rate hikes, it is an acknowledged part of the political landscape. Since 1978, the voters have proved willing to add exclusions from changes in ownership, which they presumably would not readily give up, further restricting the growth of property tax revenues. Even split-roll proposals, which would assess business property differently, have been unsuccessful with the voters. Several of the Task Force members expressed considerable concern that Proposition 13 may unfairly impact new homeowners by disproportionately increasing their property tax obligations vis-a-vis existing homeowners, thus, adversely impacting housing affordability. They also expressed concern that Proposition 13 has had the unintended effect of stifling competition in the commercial sector by forcing new or relocated businesses to absorb a higher property tax obligation com- pared with established competitors. These Task Force members believe that detailed studies of Proposition 13 winners and losers may reveal inequi- ties that could be resolved by periodi- cally reappraising commercial proper- ties and moderating the impact of higher taxes on home purchasers without increasing taxes on existing homeowners. The majority of the Task Force mem- bers felt that these types of detailed studies may be appropriate for a future focused study group, but such studies were beyond the resources of this Task Force. On a more pragmatic level, the voters have resisted prior attempts~ to treat commercial properties differently through any sort of split- roll proposals. The tax policy sub- committee concluded that any recom- mendations concerning split-roll were premature and not viable in the current political environment. Sales and Use Taxes should be Reallocated The sales and use tax historically has been an important discretionary revenue source for local govemments. The tax policy subcommittee concluded that future growth in local sales and use tax revenues should be allocated among the various local jurisdictions on a per capita basis rather than the current point-of-sale basis. The "point-of-sale" allocation of sales and use tax revenues is responsible for today's "cash-box" approach to land use planning, contrib- uting to unbalanced development (discussed in greater detail by the Task Force subcommittee on land use planning). The tax policy subcommittee focused on the local general purpose portion of the sales and use tax. Generally under- stood as a single tax, the total sales and use tax rate is actually comprised of several separate but conforming taxes. The State tax is imposed at 6%. The local sales tax is 1-1/4%, with 1% for local general purposes and the remain- ing 1/4% for transportation develop- ment. Separate transit and other special district taxes are up to 1-1/4%. While calling for a change in the current point-of-sale method of allocating local x~ sales and use tax revenues, the tax policy subcommittee felt an immediate reallocation based on population would KATHLEEN CONNELL * STATE CONTROLLER 25 not be viable. The current system has been in place for many years. Local governments and taxpayer-merchants have made land use planning and busi- ness location decisions that rely on this revenue stream. Many localities will believe they have too much already invested in this long-standing system to readily release revenues authorized by local ordinances, in compliance with the law, and on which their long-term finan- cial planning and budgeting have been based. However, it is hoped that, as localities recognize and appreciate their collective need for a well-rounded approach to community planning, they will endorse a broader and less divisive and distortlye method of allocating future growth in local sales and use tax revenue. Thus, the tax policy subcommittee recommends that future growth in local sales and use tax revenues be allocated on a per capita basis. However, the subcommittee acknowledges that an allocation that appears fair today could result in inequi- ties over time. Broaderdng the Sales and Use Tax Base The sales and use tax base is increasingly narrow. The tax policy subcommittee briefly discussed broadening the base in conjunction with lowering the rate in order to increase local discretionary funds. Sales tax exemptions traditionally have been used as a means to encourage various industries or to avoid adding a regressire burden to basic necessities, such as food. Since California's economy is increas- ingly service oriented, adding services to the base is the most logical choice for broadening the scope of the sales and use tax. However, the members of the tax policy subcommittee also noted that revenues from the addition of services would be subject to the business cycle, and strongly opposed by the business community. Therefore, the subcommittee did not make any recommendations in this area. Exchange orSales Tax for Property Tax Reversing the property tax shift of the early 1990s is a major political and financial goal for local governments. The tax policy subcommittee discussed whether a return of property tax rev- enues to local govemments should be coupled with dedication of all sales and use taxes as State General Fund rev- enues. ,The subcommittee considered mainly the general purpose local taxes. Dedicating sales and use taxes as State General Fund revenues should eliminate the distortion the current point-of-sale allocation method has caused in land use planning decisions. Trading a return of property taxes for sales and use taxes thus could be an attractive solution. However, at least two significant con- ceres arise. First, since the passage of Proposition 13 and even more so since the State created the ERAFs, local governments have focused more and more on sales and use taxes as a replace- ment for property taxes. At this point in time, the State's share of the property taxes are dwarfed by the local sales taxes. A dollar-for-dollar "swap' in the common notion is financially impossible. Second, and perhaps more important, sales and use tax, have become the primary domain of the cities. Trading a return of property taxes for the local KATHLEEN CONNELL * STATE CONTROLLER 26 sales and use tax revenues would result in a disastrous shorffall for city govern- ments. Such a trade would mean only that, instead of a property tax shift, there would be a sales and use tax shift that would cripple the high growth urban center. City governments fighfiy would perceive the trade as continued usurpa- tion of their local government revenues for the benefit of State and county government. All levels ofiocal govern- ment are seeking not only to recover the money they lost in the property tax shift, but also to generate additional revenues so they can adequately support local government services. Income and Franchise Taxes The subcommittee discussed whether the personal income and/or the corpo- rate income and franchise tax should be replaced with an alternative tax scheme such as a consumption or value-added tax. However, it was concluded that no such change should be undertaken as long as the federal income tax system remains in place. The efficiencies gained from the dual income tax system for government and taxpayers alike support continuity. Tipplers' Tax The subcommittee considered having the State authorize counties to impose a tipplers' tax, a tax on alcoholic drinks served, since counties have not been as successful as cities in locating additional discretionary revenue sources post- Proposition 13. However, a tipplers' tax would not appear to pass the analytical filters the tax policy subcom- mittee recommends. Conclusions of the Subcommittee California must renew its dialogue at the local community level to assure reven' raising authority is associated with ~ spending authority. Representative local government now must rely on the direct democracy of the ballot box to obtain needed financial resources. In a "don't tax you, don't tax me, tax that guy behind the tree" world, local government must fred ways to persuade voters that the health of the community matters to each individual and each property in the community. Listening to constituents and being accountable for financial decisions should assist in convincing voters that local governments must have authority over resources to do the job the community expects. KATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER billion intergovemment~l Accountability The greatest concern among local elected leaders is that State government officials no longer regard ~eir local cotmterparts as "parreefs" in the multidimensional challenge of providing appropriate govemmental services in the most efficient and effective manner. Instead, local offidals are convinced that California State government has been balancing its budget on the backs of municipal govemment by either confiscating traditional revenue sources or forcing localities to substantially underwrite State programs. These were the views that emerged from the discussions of the SMART Task Force subcommittee on intergovernmental State Control of Local Revenues Local governments believe they are viewed by State govemment as existing only to provide revenue to Sacramento on demand regardless of the resultant financial impact on critical local ser- vices. Overthe past seven years, the State has shifted approximately $21.5 billion in property tax monies away from local governments. Even with the historic State surplus in 1999, the State's 'qargesse" toward local governments was almost token. The State budget for fiscal year 1999-2000 provided local govemments with $150 million, half going to cities and counties based on population and the other half based on the amount of property tax the State transfers from these entities each ymr. Essentially, the State govemment has sacrificed county-run programs, most notably health, community services, and local irmastructure, to subsidize its own budget needs. The subcommittee concluded that the only way to correct this irabalance is to restore the property tax as the primary revenue source for local govemments and to minimize the impacts of the ERAF. Unfunded State Mandates The subcommittee members discussed the State' s practice of regularly disre- garding its legal and ethical obligation to fully fund expenses incurred by local governments that result from State- mandated programs or increased levels of service. Many local officials believe it is irresponsible for State elected leaders to take public credit for legislation without accurately disclosing the price tag that accompanies the new program Local governments deeply resent being compelled to comply with State- mandated programs regardless of cost, particularly when there is no adequate or timely reimbursement from the State. For example, Task Force members from relatively rural Mariposa County estimate that the new State-mandated program imposing a stringent regiman on animal control agencies forthe care of recovered animals will increase ltmt county 's annual animal control budget from $30,000 to roughly $300,000. Counties were to comply by July l, 1999. However, the State has provided no funding to absorb the cost of this program's implementation. In instances where the locality does seek reimbursement forthe costs imposed by a State mandate, the process to secure that compensatory funding is tedious, complicated, and dominated by State government interests. The complexity IGxa~.~N Co~.~.x~ · SrAr~ Co~mo~.~z~ 28 of the mandate process is demonstrated by the overview flow chart shown on the following page that was created by the Commission on State Mandates to 'Tacilitate" understanding. Meanwhile, through all the delay, local govemments face the challenge of identifying resources to self-fund the State's mandate. Given the enormous strain this places on local budgets, the subcommittee members recommended that the State be required to affix an accurate price tag to every proposed mandate and concurrently appropriate the amount of money necessary for full reimburse- ment. This would be accomplished by requiting any legislation, executive order, or State agency regulation that imposes any costs on local entities to be accompanied by an Economic Impact Projection (EIP) prepared either by the Legislative Analyst's Office or the Department of Finance. The EIP would identify the mount of annual reim- bursement to which affected local entities will be enti~ed. Every bill, executive order, or State agericy regulation subject to the EIP, including those containing an urgency clause, would be required to include a contemporaneous appropriati on to provide immediate reimbursement. The amount should equal or exceed the projected reimbursement cost identified inthe EIP. These fun& would then be deposited in the Slate Mandate Claims Fund, where they would be separately held and applied only to reimburse costs ofthe specific mandate for which they were deposited. If the funds are not deposited, local agencies would not be required to implement the new law, executive order, or regulation_ In conjunction with this recommenda- ~.~ lion, the subcommittee believes any affected local agency should be allowed to file for an injunction seeldng a Preliminmy Stay of Operation of any portion of any statute, executive order, or State agency regulation while atest claim is pending before the Commission on State Mandates. The Slay should be- issued unless the State establishes by a preponderance of the evidence that the reimbursement funds deposited in the State Mandate Claims Fund for the specific mandate are equal to at least 75% ofth,.e reasonably projected costs of the mandate. Such a stay would remain in effect until one of the following occurs: 1) A supplemental deposit is made bringing the deposit to a level equal to 75% of the reasonably projected costs, as ~w~J detemined by the court; 2) The Commission on State Mandates issues a Statement of Decision denying the claim and issuing the Statewide Esti- mate of Costs forthe mandate; or 3) The local agency abandons its claim This State respomibility for maldng full Icial disclosure should commence the day the mandate takes effect. State and Loeal Partnerships Currently, there are more than 100 programs funded by the Slate and administered through local govemmenis that display the potential for tree intergovernmental cooperation, where each partner is accountable to the other. The subcommittee believes such partnerships should be encouraged. In addition, the subcommittee feels local ~, entities that administer State-funded programs have an obligation to strictly account for the manner in which those KATULE~.N CONNELL · STEE CONr~OX. LE~. 29 STAR1 Fina~ .:xr,~ 510 CSM He~ri.,~ edi:,i~s _.~~ to parties 18'3 Ercma~ 525 ~ ~ ~4~ mt"dm°ns'ae;igibleenC';iswi!hin~Ods)su( Staffdeve~apss'aL~ide + receivin~mead°rc"dP&G:s c~ e~,imate (SC~; II a~l;~m.~ an L~i age~les file rei.q~.'smem claims wm m SCO, p~epares ar,2.i)'sis a~ ~ and f~a are SCO aud ..u and pa~s reim~lrs~mnm rla ires ' recnmrne~lati{x', mails available. the ~a.'.e · ~ cJate Mande~Ciaim. s Yes Fun~ {SMCF) CMSH~qrn~ ParameL~ & Guidelines adopt~ t30 , 150 Final p~c. pesa; i '-' I I C~S Hearing SOD K~THLEEN CONNELL ' STATE CONTROLLER 30 a ~m~g web go~r~men~td s~q~o~ the ,~eeds ~/~ts funds are spent. To promote this objective, the subcom- mittee recommended that where such parmerships are created, the State and local entities should enter into bilateral compacts that incorporate the specific expectations and obligations of each party. Included within these compacts would be a commitment by the State to fully fund and the locality to effectively implement some forms of performance. based budgeting and performance auditing that would be appropriate to the specific program The subcommittee members also felt local governmentS should engage in revenue sharing when it is coupled with shared responsibility for services to the public. For example, some Task Force members said Sutter andYuba counties are partnering in the delivery of mental health services to their residentS. Such consolidated approaches have the potential for offering more comprehen- sive services in a cost-efficient manner than either of the partnering entities might be able to offer on its own. Local govemments should be given tools that will encourage, where appropriate, consolidated approaches to difficult financing and service delivery chal- lenges. This als6 will minimize inter- governmental rivalties for scarce resources. Concl~ions ~f the ,Subcommittee The State should be able to rely on local govemments to competenfly administer State-funded programs, but ~he fiscal health and viability of those local govemments will determine their effectiveness as administrators. Super- /mposing additional budgeting and auditing controls on local govemment~ such as perfommnc~based budgeting ~; or performance auditing, without a stipend to absorb the costS is fll advise& Local leaders would welcome any new approach that will make govemment spending more efficient and effective as long as the costs of additional auditing services can be passed through to the State, and the Slate will live up to its obligations. Local governmentS carmot be treated as "colonies of Sacramento," ffCalifomia is to rebuild the strong web of govern- mental supportthat so effectively served the needs of its citizens in the past To act othgnvise would ultimately destroy the entire system of govemment in Calffomia by eroding the foundation of local govemment KATHLEEN CONNELL ' STATE CONTROLLER 31 premier s~rc~: qf L~nd Use The land use planning subcommittee found Lhat inappropriate land use decisions are being made in large part due to the State-local m structure. While recommendations to revise this structure were left to the Task Force's tax policy subcommittee to develop, the land use subcommittee focused onhow future land use derision-making would be improved, fithe fiscal relationship between California State government and local govemments was altered. Proposition 13 and the Fiscalization of Land Use Since passage of proposition 13 in 1978, the State has controlled the distribution of tax revenues among local govemments. Local govemments' property tax revenues have plummeted over the last two decades, in part, due to Proposition 13. To compensate for deep cuts in property taxes, local govemments have increased developer fees and homeowner charges to fund the s ervi ces that new residential and commercial developments require, such as roads, parks, sewers, schools, and police and fire protection. While the fees typically are for long- term funding of such services, the hio~her up-front costs hinder develop- ment Local govemments may deny approval for new developments, or make approval hard to obtain, if it is deemed the development will not pay its way in terms of funding services. One -ldnd ofpermitting bias that has grown in the post-Proposition 13 em works against moderate- income homeo wners. Local govemments have come to favor upscale homes with large lots over small er-lot homes because the former represent lower housing density and hence lower infrastructure costs. Proposition 13 has skewed land use and economic development in anumber of ways that do notnecessarily serve the community's best interests. Retail growth is now preferred over manufac- lining and other industrial growth because it generates sales tax revenues. Financially slruggling ciries and counties compete to attract shopping mails, discount clubs, and auto malls. In many cases, neighboring cities have launched bidding wars to attract big retailers while looking skeptically at prospective manufacttmg or R&D developments. Given strong public support of Proposi- tion 13, efforts to revise it to address these stifling effects on growth and rebuild depleted infrasmlcture have met stiff opposition. The collective effect of these trends is that the sales tax is now the premier source of revenue for local govern- ments. Fartoo often, local officials are setting aside sound planning principles as th~ compete for revenue-producing projects, a phenomenon that has become known as the '~i~calization of land-use." The land use planning subcommittee concluded that reform of the tax structure, which was dealt with by the Task Force subcommittee on tax policy, is critical to restoring the appropriate balance in land use decision make. The ERAF Shifi Although the property tax shifts played a critical role in helping Califomia resolve its severe budget difficulties in the early 1990s, these shifts also negatively affected local govemments' incentive to approve new land develop- I(&THLEEN CONNELL ' STATE CONTROLLER ments and, to alesser degree, to prope~y administer the property tax collection system Local govemmmts do not have as much control over property taxes as they did in the past, and property taxes are no longer as high apriority forthem. Forthis reason, the land use planning subcommittee believes State lawmakers should phase out the ERAF shift as soon as possible. Housing Aside from land use issues related to the tax structure, the subcommittee found homing to be the most critical land use challenge facing Calffomia. Currently, business andj ob growth do not balance with housing growth. Many jobs have been created due to the economic boom in Califomia, which also has driven up the demand forhousing. However, new residential construction has been somewhat slower in parts of Califomia~ For example, in 1998 in Orange County, there were 61,000 new jobs created, but only 10,000 building pen-nits were issue& The location of housing is another key concem. California nee& to develop incentives fcir people to live relatively close to their workplace. Business leaders are demanding affordable housing to attract talent to Califomia (especially in high growth areas such as the Silicon Valley). Employees also want affordable housing near their workplace. To address these needs, the subcommittee believes stronger incen- fives should be put in place to increase construction of affordable housing, including multi-family dwellings, in urban centers. In addition, many older neighbonhoods need to be improved and maintained. This 'should include construction of new schools and job, training centers. Improving the livability~ of urban centers will increase private sector investment in those communities and help stem tlight to the suburbs. Construction Defect Lit~,ation Litnits Multi-Family Housing Construction Since the 1980s, new multi-family residential coustmction has been falling as a percentage of total residential construction. The major mason forthis tremendous drop is that construction defect litigation has opened the door to unnecessary lawsuits against the owners . ofnew multi-family dwellings. Devel- opers of multi.family housing face the added burden of strict liability for construction defects and a 1 O-year period when a suit may be filed. This, in tum, has resulted in both contractors and subcontractors being unable to obtain insurance. Although California needs more multi-family housing, current litigation practices have all but stopped its construction. The subcommittee concluded that State law needs to be changed to increase the incentives for multi-family and entry- level housing. Regional Needs w the 'iNimby' Syndrome Many communities that are experienc- ing a sharp increase innewjobs, such as San Francisco, also have agrowing need forhigh-density housing. How- ever, the communities themselves generally oppose more high-density housing due to its local impact on open space, congestion, and aesthetics. '~Not in my back yard" arguments often prevail over regional planning goals. The land use planning subcommittee K~x~xs.~.r~ CONNELX~ · ST~E Com~o~.usR 33 considered whether financial incen- tives should be developed to reward communities with "growth" polides, which would not be available to communilies with "no growth" policies. However, no recommenda- lions were made in this area_ California Housing Finance Author- ity and R elated A geneies California has 11 of the 25 least affordable communities in the entire nation. To combat ils shortage Of affordable housing, California created the Califomia Housing Finance Author- ity (CHFA). Acting as the State' s mortgage bank, the CHFA offers below-market rate mortgage financing to meet the homing needs of low- to moderate-income families. Assembly Bill 1404 (Dutra), introduced this year, would increase the CHFA' s debt limit ~ from $6.75 billion to $8.95 billior~ The subcommittee strongly encourages all such measures to increase funding for, and consequently the availability of, affordable housing. At the same time, Califomia should review how these funds are allocated to ensure that innovative plans that address the greatest housing needs are being funded. Military Bases for Housing The closure of military bases represents a potential partial solution to the shortage of affordable housing in Califomia~ Especially in Northem California, military bases generally are located near urban centers. The land could be used for what it already provides, for example, housing. How- ever, as seen in other parts of the State, these bases may become sites for large retail or commercial ventures instead of housing. While the land use planning subcommittee was favorably im- pressed with the concept of using dosed military bases for expanding the availability of affordable housing in urban areas, it did not make a specific recommendation. Inpastructure Lack of infrastructure funding in recent years has become a major crisis for Califomia_ As with other issues addressed by the SMART Task Fome, the availability of resources for this purpose has been largely dictated by the fiscal relationship between the State and local governments. The subcommittee noted that local entities would be better able to address the infrastructure challenges that surround them, including outdated sewer systems and roadways, if they were allocated more than the small portion of property lax they currently receive. Currently, as they lack the resources, city governments are taking two actions to address infrastructure needs: raising developer and home- owner charges and opting for develop- ment ofupscale homes with large lots over smaller homes. The subcommittee recommends that an increase in funding for infrastructure should be used in support of affordable housing and modemizing infrastructure in urban areas. Decaying downtowns should be rebuilt and modemized. The effect of suburban and edge-city sprawl will be greatly improved through funding for transportation, mixed use in-fill, and habitat protection. Performance-Based Funding f or Inpastructure KATHLEEN CONNELL * STATE CONTROLLER 34 A common problem with funding infrastructure projects is the lack of data on project effectiveness. Where data is collected, there is little nexus between the project's success and future funding. For example, the State has apportioned hundreds of millions of dollars to improve public transpor- tation, but statistics have shown that the increased funding did not translate into increased ridership. Often, government support for these types of projects is not contingent on Showing the effectiveness of the spending. The subcommittee concluded that, ff the State increases the use of perfor- mance measures when allocating resources, those resources will be used more efficien~y, and only where they provide significant benefit. Increasing Local Government Commtmication The subcommittee discussed the need for local governments to improve communications with respect to infra- structure spending, thus enhancing efficiency. California should consider adopting several city planning proce- dures within the optional elements of the general plan guidelines published by the Governor's Office of Planning and Research. The State should provide fiscal incentives to encourage cities to follow one of the adopted measures. However, the subcommittee concluded that specific guidelines should be developed by a joint Task Force of State and local officials, rather than the SMART Task Force. Land Use Objectives for the 21st Centtny The land use planning subcommittee determined that certain objectives ~.~ should guide local governments in planning their communities. After much deliberation, the subcommittee developed the criteria it believes should guide this decision-making, with particular attention to the differences between new develop- ment and existing development. These criteria are described below. New Communities - Ideally, new communities in California should be integrated so they include housing, shops, work places, schools, parks, and civic facilities that are essential to the daily life of the residents. Community size should be designed so that housing, jobs, daily needs, and other activities are within easy walking distance of each other. These communities should include diverse housing types, enabling ~: citizens from a wide range of economic levels and age groups to live within its boundaries. Urban Communities - The subcommit- tee agreed that urban communities often lack a central focus that combines commercial, dvic, cultural, and recre- ational i/ses within easy walking distance of transit stops. Each commu- nity or duster of communities should have a well-defined edge, such as agricultural greenbelts or wileRife corridors, permanently protected from development. Regional land use planning structure should be integrated within a larger transportation network built around transit rather than free- ways. Regional institutions and services (e.g., government offices, stadiums, and museums) would be located in the urban core. Existing Communities - The subcom- KATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER 35 mittee concluded that the ~nandal and time costs necessary to achieve these ideals in existing metropolitan communities are too high in relation to the results achieved. In developed areas, California must use existing social and physical infrastructure while permitting in-fill and intercon- nected communities. However, by improving land use decision-making, communities can achieve cleaner air and water, less traffic congestion and more affordable housing while reversing and/or controlling sprawl, at the lowest possible social and financial costs. Conclusions of the Subcommittee The fiscal realities of the post- Proposition 13 worId create great disincentives for wise land use policy in California. Until those fiscal factors are addressed, California's local governments will continue to forego "smart" growth in favor of new revenue sources. Each community in Califomia is unique. The State government should be wary of mandating local land use processes. Rather, the State should focus on providing adequate fmandal resources for those communities to make their own land use planning dealsions. Given adequate resources, local govemments are far more likely to make balanced and appropriate plan- ning dealsions, which will protect open spaces, promote adequate housing, and improve California's economy. KATHLEEN CONNELL * STATE CONTROLLER Appendix ~A Percentage of Locai Revenues & Expenditures for California Cities and Counties for the Period ofJu~y ~, 1993 through June 30, I997 Cities Revenues 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 Sendee Charges (Sewage, Water, Electricity) 41% 41% 4t% 39% Sales and Use Taxes 10 10 10 9 State and Federal Taxes 12 13 13 13 Property Taxes 7 7 7 6 Revenues from Use of Monies and Property 4 4_ 5 4 Utility Taxes 4 4 4 4 Business License Tax 2 2 2 2 Licenses and Permits 1 1 1 1 Transportation Tax 1 2 2 1 Other. 18 16 15 21 Total 100% 100% 100% 100% Counties Revenues 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 StateAid 42% 39% 42% 43% FederalAid 22 21 21 21 Property Taxes 15 11 12 12 Service Charges, Miscelaneous Revenues and Other Financing Sources 12 21 17 15 "~I~/ Sales Tax and Other Taxes 3 3 3 3 Other 6 5 5 6 Total 100% 100% 100% 100% Cities Expenditures 1993-94 1994-95 1995-% 1996-97 Public Safety (Police, Fire, Paramedics) 26% 26% 26% 26% Public Utilities (Gas, Electricity, Water) 21 21 20 20 Cornmunit~ Development and Health 21 21 22 22 Transportation (Streets) 15 15 15 15 Parks, Recreation, Libraries 8 9 9 8 General Govcmm,nent 9 8 8 9 Total 100% 100% 100% 100% Counties Expenditures 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 Public Assistance (Welfare) 41% 38% 40% 38% Public Protection (Gas, Electricity, Water) 27 25 28 29 Health and Sanitation 17 14 14 16 Administration and Elections 9 15 9 9 Roads 3 3 3 3 Education, Recreation, Culture, Debt Service 3 5 6 5 Total 100% 100% 100% 100% Source: Stale Controller' s Office Annual Financial Transaction Reports KATI{LEEN CONNELL ' STATE CONTROLLER 37 Appendix B Education Revenue Augmentation Fund (ERAF) Shif~ (Amounts in Thousands) ~1992-93 '1993-94 1994-95 '1995-96 '1996-97 Alameda 71.413 176.746 190.541 191.974 195.207 Alpine 22 131 22 150 152 Amador 558 1,997 2,019 2.110 2.120 Butte 3,773 12,689 13,243 11,302 10,081 Calaveras 1,041- 2.614 2,887 3.013 3,107 Colusa 411 1,420 1,475 1,525 1,651 Contra Costa 40.962 98,986 110,826 101.701 105,381 Del Norte 339 1,127 1.282 1,508 1.344 El Dorado 4,910 11,010 11.166 11,592 12,025 Fresno 17,108 63,538 65, 148 66,998 68.560 Glenn 592 1,845 1.963 2,001 2,049 Humboldt 3,021 9.740 10.172 10,655 11.085 Imperial 2.220 9.491 10.164 10,473 9, 949 Inyo 516 1,970 1,956 1.887 1,783 Kern 13,087 51,583 46.163 51,499 51.901 Kings 2.581 8.325 8.951 9,110 8.873 Lake 2,154 4,556 4,555 4,610 4.635 Lessen 366 1.369 1.275 1,494 1.391 Los Angeles 460.656 1,280,693 1,162,638 1.139, 190 1,123,618 Madera 1.785 4.376 7.777 8,112 8,334 Madn 11,640 29.847 31.158 32,212 33,259 Mariposa 159 751 860 852 863 Mendocino 1,734 4,123 6,718 6.986 7,319 M erced · 4.821 15,752 16.457 16,353 17,864 M odo c 195 726 733 789 702 Mono 730 1,620 1,857 1,782 1,805 Monterey 8,952 27,232 28,147 29,637 30.294 Nape 3,026 10,997 11,397 11,671 12,058 Neveda 1,598 6.772 7.106 7,489 7,705 Orange 100,790 266,326 263.291 256,668 258,394 , ~"'~lacer 6,099 19.190 19,804 21,018 22.152 lumas 419 1.179 1.452 1.393 1.446 Riverside 42,395 101,442 100,987 101,248 100,470 Sacramento 33,520 92,601 119,029 120, 312 121,027 San Benlto 1.125 2,555 2.445 2,550 2.536 San Bernardino 52,952 61,795 122,948 124,230 127,236 San Diego 53.115 118.687 193,143 195.402 195.788 San Francisco 53,906 136,249 139,667 130.444 133,975 San Joequirt 15,533 57.246 58,568 60,510 61,723 San Luis Obispo 6,448 19,909 21,443 21.632 21,954 San Mateo 19,405 74,505 76.101 77,125 79,427 Santa Barbara 10,724 30,256 31,379 32,042 32,951 Santa Clara 58.524 134. 577 166,292 166, 834 171,152 Santa Cruz 5.913 19,444 19,971 20,577 20.727 Shasta 2.704. 11,896 12.471 12.917 12.485 Sierra 143 ' 284 303 310 318 Siskiyou 900 2.906 3.097 3,408 3,523 $olano _ 15,758 32.384 34,670 37.499 36,571 Sonoma 11,709 35,935 37.634 37,654 38,205 Stanislaus 5.243 28.201 28.517 29.002 29.206 Sutter 1,657 5.968 6.161 6,312 6.620 Tehama 924 3,272 3,567 3,760 3,899 Trinity 113 393 487 508 539 Tulare 8,036 27,267 28,703 29,891 30.658 Tuolumne 1.267 3,492 3,919 3.862 4,098 Venture 26.523 63,070 68,900 70,154 71,003 Yolo 4.364 14,228 15.925 16.735 16,929 Yuba 1 371 4 511 4 gR4 4 gRr} 4 Total 1 201 900 3 21t 995 3 3s4 512 3 327 654 3 345 080 1997-98 1998-99 207.221 217.426 169 174 2.433 2,438 10,461 10.869 3,197 3.355 1,739 1,812 105.925 110.731 1.437 1,474 12.448 13,072 70.153 71.928 2,076 2.164 11,493 11.906 7.461 9,479 1.816 1.760 56.068 . 53,285 9,394 9,668 4,753 4.831 1.455 "' 1,551 1,140.069 1,142,036 8,771 9,164 35,037 36,947 968 994 7,674 8,341 17,419 18,224 718 732 1,643 1.887 32,031 33.725 12,591 13.318 7,966 8,320 267,539 283, 108 23,073 24,877 1,612 1,691 101,026 104,645 122,089 127,312 2,552 2.757 130,511 133,188 202,003 215, 277 138,524 152,317 64,201 66,251 22,695 23,451 83,780 90.783 34,418 37224 184,753 209,795 21,513 22,654 13,211 13,520 319 345 3,667 3,720 37,118 38,165 39,541 41,504 29,805 30,609 6,771 6,964 4,010 4,136 546 519 31,806 32,808 4,200 4,306 70,518 73269 16,894 18,332 5 049 5 775 3 438 527 3 570 913 Source: SCO's Annual Report of Property Taxes for the 1992-93 Through 1998-99 Fiscal Year Fiscal Year 1997-1998 ERAF Contributions Contributions Counties $ 2,656.218,449 Cities 5?6 698 06? Subject to swap · 3,182,916,511 Special Districts 255 610 808 $ 3.438.527.319 I~ATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER Append ix C Notes to Alemate Ptans and ths "SMART Formula" After discussion of the merits and drawbacks of several methods that might be used to reallocate sales taxes, and to offset local govemmenls forthe lost property tax revenues associated with the creation of the Educational Revenue Augmentation Fund (ERAF), the following methodology was used for computing the information in Altema- fives 1 through 3. In order to reallocate sales taxes based more on a county' s population, rather than where the sale occurred, the current percentage of sales tax revenues distributed by county, and the percent- age of population by county were computed. First, information from the State Board of Equalization' s 1997- 1998 Annual Keport, the latest report available, was obtained. Sales tax infonmtion from Table 21A- Revenues Distributed to Cities and Counties from the Local Sales and Use Taxes, was summarized to provide the total sales tax revenues for counties and cities. This total therefore represents what a county would normally receive on 1% of taxable sales. Informalion on population by county was obtained from the Department of Finance' s Population Certification letter dated July 22, 1999. The proportionate statewide percentage oflimt county's population to total population was computed by dividing the county' s population by the statewide total population. After the percentages were obtained for countywide sales tax revenues disaib- uted and population by county, these percentages were weighted and then multiplied by the total statewide sales tax revenues distributed in fiscal year 1997-1998. This was done to determine the impact of weighting some of the sales tax revenue distribution on population versus point-of-sale. The p~rcentages were weighted in the following manner, sales taxes by point-of-sale, i.e. sims, were multiplied by 90%, while sales tax distributed by population was multiplied by 10%. Finally, in order to provide the counties with some relieffrom the ERAIF shift; which first occurred in fiscal year 1992- 1993, we allocated $450 million to these counties based on the percentage of the ERAF shift forthe fiscal year 1997-1998. Informati on from the State Controller's Office' s 1997-1998 Annual Report of Property Taxes was used in most cases. Forthe counties not providing the breakdown of the ERAF shift by county and city for 1997-1998, 1998-1999 data was used to eslimate the 1997-1998 information. KATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER 39 State Controller Kathleen Connell wishes to extend her heartfelt thanks to all the individuals whose hard work and dedication made this report possible. TAT r '~'IUNICIPAL Taskforce Membership Hon. Richard Alarc6n State Senator Hon. Doug Balmain Mariposa Board of Supervisors Chair of Accountability Subcommittee Hon. Ed Edelman Rand Corporation Len Frank Pardee Construction David French Regional Counci] on Rural Coun- ties Mark Gaughan San Diego Gas & Electric Com- pany Travis Gibbs, Esq. O'Me]veny & Meyers AnneHe Gra, jeda SEIU- Local 660 I-Ion. Lucy Killea S. D. international Community Foundation Pius Lee California Realty & Land Inc. Hon. Gloria Molina L.A. County Board of Supervisors Chair of Taxes Subcommittee Dowell Myers, PhD USC - School of Policy, Planning and Development Hon. Beverly 0 'Neill Mayor of Long Beach Hon. Julie Partax;sky Mayor of Davis Chair of Land Use Subcommittee Hon. Judy Pennycook Monterey Board of Supervisors Mark Pisano Southern California Association of Governments George Popyack AFSCME Hon. George Runner State Assembly Member Steven Szalay California State Association of Counties Jeff Vesely, Esq. Pilsbury, Madison. & Sutro Tom W'mfield, Esq. Brown, Winfield & Canzoneri, Inc. KATHLEEN CONNELL · STATE CONTROLLER 40